Saturday, January 30, 2010
Endogeneity
Table 21.6 presents regression models on the determinants of exit outcomes
that are similar to those in Table 21.5 but with one major exception. In Table
21.6, we examine the effect of endogeneity of control rights on exits. We use
two-step instrumental variable estimates. Step 1 of Models 3 and 4 accounts
for the factors that affect the extent of VC control. Step 1 of Model 3 considers binomial logit estimates for majority board seats and the right to replace
the CEO. Step 1 of Model 4 considers ordered logit estimates of the control
rights index for the sum of dummy variables for drag-along, redemption, and
antidilution rights. Step 2 of Models 3 and 4 estimates the multinomial logit
model of exit outcomes.
In Table 21.6 , we use the exogenous variables that are included in step 1 and
excluded in step 2 of Models 3 and 4. These variables are the La Porta et al.
(1998) indexes for creditor rights and antidirector (shareholder) rights. These
instruments are intuitively related to contract terms, as confirmed by all of the
correlations that are reported in Table 21.7 . We do not expect to find a relation
between creditor rights and exit outcomes, unless the efficiency of bankruptcy
law is related to write-offs. Table 21.7 indicates that creditor rights are not
statistically related to any of the exit outcomes, which confirms the suitability
of that instrument for the data. Antidirector rights may be positively related to
the probability of an IPO (La Porta et al., 1998), but the data here indicate the
opposite. The correlation between antidirector rights and IPO exits is 0.18.
This negative correlation can only be explained by independent factors driving
the IPO exits, and by little or no direct relation between IPOs and antidirector
rights. In contrast, the antidirector rights index is significant and negatively
related to the contract terms. This finding is consistent with the view that as
shareholders, VCs use contracts as substitutes for the absence of strong legal
protection (Lerner and Schoar, 2005). Creditor rights are positively and significantly related to contract terms, which is intuitive, because when decisions
have be made in times of financial distress, VCs as shareholders want priority
over and above creditors. Also, we use the industry market/book value at the
time of first investment as an instrumental variable. This is a valid instrument
because the second-step regressions use the industry market/book value at the
time of exit. The results of the second step regressions are similar when we use
the different instruments and different specifications for the first-step regressions and are available on request.
In Table 21.6 , the step 1 evidence in Models 3 and 4 indicates that creditor
rights are statistically and positively related to the extent of VC control and to
the right to replace the CEO, but not statistically related to majority board seats.
A one-point increase in the creditor rights index (on the scale of zero to four)
increases the probability of the VC acquiring the right to replace the CEO by
31.6%. We note that although the creditor and antidirector rights are negatively
correlated ( 0.42 for this sample), the statistical and economic significance of
the regressions is not materially affected by the inclusion or exclusion of these
variables. For instance, excluding antidirector rights in step 1 of Model 3 in Table 21.6 increases the economic significance of creditor rights from 31.6
to 34.3% for the right to replace the CEO without changing the statistical
significance.
A one-point increase in the creditor rights index also increases the probability of an extra control right (drag-along, redemption, or antidilution) by on
average approximately 3%. The economic significance of a one-point increase
in creditor rights is 4.9% to move from two to three, and 2.6% to move from
three to four in step 1 of Model 4.
In contrast, antidirector rights are more closely tied to majority board seats.
An increase of one point in the index (on the scale of 0 to 6) reduces the probability of VC majority board seats by 12.6%. The step 1 regressions in Table 21.6
further indicate that VCs are more likely to have a majority on the board and
to have greater control rights for those firms in industries with higher market/
book ratios (high-tech industries). VCs are less likely to take majority board
seats, have the right to replace the CEO, and to have other control rights for
earlier-stage investments. VCs are also less likely to have the right to replace
the CEO and other control rights when the entrepreneur has a higher experience ranking.
The step 2 regressions in Models 3 and 4 in Table 21.6 are consistent with
those reported for Models 1 and 2 in Table 21.5 . Majority board seats lead to
a 22.3% increase in the probability of an acquisition exit (Model 3), and each
additional control right increases the probability of an acquisition by 14.5%
(Model 4). The one result that differs from Models 1 and 2 is that the right to
replace the CEO is statistically insignificant in Model 3.
In general, the alternative specifications for the step 1 and 2 regressions in
Table 21.6 invariably support at least one of the VC control right variables
as being significantly related to acquisition exits. The instrumental variables
regressions are not completely robust to alternative specifications, but nevertheless indicate support for the central proposition in the chapter that VC
control influences the IPO versus acquisition choice, even after controlling for
endogeneity.